The Downfall of Money: Germany’s Hyperinflation and the Destruction of the Middle Class (40 page)

Read The Downfall of Money: Germany’s Hyperinflation and the Destruction of the Middle Class Online

Authors: Frederick Taylor

Tags: #Business & Money, #Economics, #Inflation, #Money & Monetary Policy, #Finance, #History, #Europe, #Germany, #Professional & Technical, #Accounting & Finance

BOOK: The Downfall of Money: Germany’s Hyperinflation and the Destruction of the Middle Class
10.79Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

In the excitement of the post-Ruhr invasion period, on 23 February 1923 the Reichstag, including the Social Democrats, passed an ‘emergency law’. This allowed the Cuno government to introduce, without recourse to legislation, changes in welfare, financial, economic and judicial regulations that would normally require the Reichstag’s approval.

Within the framework of these new government powers, stricter penalties for profiteering, unjustified raising of prices, the black market and transgressions against import and export restrictions were immediately announced. Finally, the government hoped, this would enable them to get a grip on prices, which were blamed precisely on profiteering by retailers.

There were two other prongs to the government’s anti-inflation attack. The government also began to publicise an internal dollar (that is, gold-backed) loan that would pay 120 per cent in 1926 (in gold, not paper marks), and which would thereby raise, it was proposed, $200 million to bolster the financial exertions needed to support passive resistance in the Ruhr. The aim was to soak up some of the massive quantities of gold and foreign exchange held by German corporations and individuals. The appeal was to patriotism, as it had been in 1914. And, secondly, the Reichsbank was prevailed upon (initially unwillingly, it must be said), to use its already existing, and surprisingly well-stocked, gold and foreign exchange reserves to support the mark, which had tumbled in value to around 40,000 to the dollar at the end of January.
1

The government’s fear was that if the mark fell any further, the essential imports of food and coal from abroad necessary to survive the ever-tightening French stranglehold on the Ruhr would become unaffordable. Astonishingly, though the jury remained out on the success of the internal dollar loan (to which Stinnes, ominously, refused to contribute a single dollar, guilder, pound or Swiss franc), the mark did come down in February 1923, and as a result of systematic and complex selling action by the bank, stayed down. For a while, British coal remained affordable and could replace the German coal impounded by the French in the Ruhr. Again, for a while.

Astonishingly, with the mark hovering at around 21,000 to the dollar, the new ‘Goldilocks level’, there were still those heavy industrialists who felt that it was too high for their export purposes. They pressured Havenstein of the Reichsbank to nudge the rate down to between 23,000 and 25,000.

Inflation had become an addiction. And, like all addictions, the stronger its hold, the more damage it inflicts on the body of the addict. Until, sooner or later, it reaches the point where it is a question of detox or die.

 

The domestic wholesale prices that dictated what ordinary people paid for the necessities of life had risen with the fall in the mark’s value to 40,000 to the dollar in the weeks immediately following the occupation of the Ruhr. However, when the Reichsbank’s support effort managed to all but halve that rate later in the month, there was no corresponding fall. True, prices by and large stabilised, but the consumer got almost no relief. Clearly producers, manufacturers and retailers did not sufficiently trust the turnaround on the exchanges to actually reduce their prices to ordinary customers as a result of the improvement in the currency.
2
If that was so, then they were right. The holding of the mark in the low 20,000s lasted longer than many observers expected – eleven weeks – but, finally, in the third week of April 1923, the dam broke.

There were any number of reasons. The dollar loan was drastically undersubscribed, proving that not enough of the real holders of wealth in Germany were prepared to underwrite the Ruhr passive resistance. It also became clear that the French were not going to give up. The mines were starting to produce again – not at the pre-occupation levels, but enough to show that the passive resistance was not having the hoped-for effect. Above all, Cuno’s government faced the crippling expense of the Ruhr passive resistance. Berlin had promised compensation for the Ruhr industrialists who continued the policy of non-cooperation, who shut down their mills and blast furnaces, plus support for workers rendered unemployed by the non-cooperation policy. Moreover, there were the wages due to the tens of thousands of railway officials and civil servants who had been expelled by the French and decanted into Germany proper, where they were being paid by their employer, the government, to do nothing.

Germany was now producing and exporting drastically less than before the occupation. All the costs of passive resistance could be covered only by the printing of German currency on a massive scale. Apart from the main State Printing Office in Berlin, 130 other print works were involved in satisfying the near-infinite demand for paper currency. The situation was such that even the most energetic activities of the Reichsbank’s currency exchange department could not keep the mark to dollar rate within bounds. By April, it was calculated that if the run on the mark continued, exacerbated by demands for foreign exchange from German businesses, the bank would be able to hold out for only another ten days before its reserves were exhausted.

In short, the support for the mark might have worked over a longer period, but only if Cuno had managed to pull off a diplomatic coup, or if the French had failed to make their occupation work. Neither of these had occurred. Neither the British nor the Americans, though they expressed disapproval of the Ruhr occupation, were prepared to put real pressure on the French to desist. And whatever the faults of the notoriously fractious French polity, in the matter of the Ruhr occupation, for the moment, it stood firm almost to a man. If the point of Cuno’s administration had been some kind of ordering of the country’s finances, his ‘business’ chancellorship might have made sense. In fact, the point was facing down the French, for which a tough and cunning diplomat was required.
3

On 18 April, the mark, which had stood at 21,100 to the dollar four days earlier, had fallen in value to 25,000. It hit 29,900 a week later, in another week 34,275, next 42,300, and by the end of May 54,300. A month later, a greenback got its lucky owner 114,250 German marks. These were fantastical seeming figures, but in July they got even worse. The world had given up on the German currency.
The Times
wrote on 20 July that ‘the Berlin Foreign Exchange Market has become a farce’,
4
while the
Manchester Guardian
’s financial editor commented on 24 July, ‘it seems almost idle to go on chronicling the complete disintegration of Germany’s financial system’.
5
The paper’s correspondent in Berlin went even further a few days later. ‘The mark,’ he reported, ‘is becoming impracticable as a medium of exchange.’
6

At the end of that month, the mark was exchangeable against the dollar for a seven-figure sum: 1,100,000. A week later, on 7 August, the rate was 3,300,000. In the course of sixteen weeks, the value of the mark had deteriorated to 1/130 of its already miserable equivalence in April, and around 1/700,000 of its long-forgotten pre-war value.

The German currency was now not just catastrophically diminished, but near enough worthless.

 

While the politicians, bankers and business leaders feared for the country and agonised over how to keep the economy halfway viable in the face of the Ruhr catastrophe, for ordinary Germans life in the summer of 1923 turned into a desperate game of pass-the-parcel. The problem was that you had to have a parcel to pass. If all you had was paper money, you were doomed. The social consequences of the inflation that had until now been only partly visible, or visible only to those with a critical eye, became impossible to ignore.

People with average incomes, and no access to agricultural produce or foreign exchange, were forced to hunt and queue for food - both because their incomes more often than not did not stretch to buying what they wanted on a particular day but also because there was, as the hyperinflation tightened its grip, a genuine shortage of food. With foreign exchange for importing food running short, and German farmers ever less willing to part with their produce for increasingly worthless paper money, the promise was of starvation amidst plenty.

In the diary of August Heinrich von der Ohe, the schoolteacher-cum-farmer on the north German plain, the entries between October 1922 and February 1923 are overwhelmingly about buying and selling. The route to survival in this crisis was clearly not through an academic salary:

 

30 October 1922:

Prices have undergone a huge increase. Rye 14,000 marks, coarse barley 9000 marks, a hundredweight of straw 2000 marks. Bought a farm cart from Schied for 125,000 marks. You have to pay 9000 marks for a ham.

 

2 December 1922:

In Celle I bought a pair of boots for 7980 marks. Straw costs 500 marks a hundredweight.

 

14 December 1922:

I bought a steer for 215,000 marks. The year and our money is at an end.

 

Today begins the year 1923:

What else will this year bring to us all?

 

6 January 1923:

Bought a second cow from Imker Rabe [probably a farmer neighbour] for 400,000 marks.

 

8 January 1923:

Salary from 1 January with supplement for December amounts to 310,000 marks.

 

18 January 1923:

The dollar has risen to 25,000 marks.

 

26 January 1923:

Sold a pig weighing 226 pounds, at 1300 marks per pound; next week it will be 1500.

 

3 February 1923:

The dollar stood at almost 50,000 marks. Rye costs 60,000 marks per hundredweight; pork 3000 marks per pound. I want to sell our cow. 1¼ million has been offered, but I want 1½. Sold our old cart for 200,000 marks. Sold a used plough for 35,000 marks. A pound of unrationed bread cost 900 marks. I was in money difficulties on many occasions, but successfully found my way out of them.

Recently bought: 1 cart for 125,000 marks, a steer for 215,000 marks, a cow for 400,000 marks, 3 piglets for 90,000 marks. For this I borrowed 425,000 marks; from my salary came a further 440,000 marks.
7

 

For many Germans, especially after the French occupation of the Ruhr, conditions had returned to something like those they had experienced during the Allied blockade between 1914 and 1919 and had fervently hoped never to experience again. In what was rapidly becoming a barter economy, the agile and the cunning, not to mention dishonest, citizen was top of the Darwinian heap.

Earlier in the year, a Barcelona newspaper,
La Veu de Catalunya
, sent a journalist to report on the situation in Berlin. Even as the Reichsbank struggled to keep the mark from total collapse, Eugeni Xammar wondered at the chaotic conditions that pertained in the third largest city in the Western world.

 

The price of tram rides and beef, theatre tickets and school, newspapers and haircuts, sugar and bacon, is going up every week. As a result, no one knows how long their money will last, and people are living in constant fear, thinking of nothing but eating and drinking, buying and selling. There is only one topic on everyone’s lips in Berlin: the dollar, the mark, and prices . . . Have you seen this? For heaven’s sake, stop! I’ve just bought a six-week supply of sausages, ham and cheese.
8

 

Almost everyone in a position to do so demanded to be paid on moveable values, or in food. Doctors and dentists had for some time since demanded cash rather than cheques or payment on account, and now in rural areas demanded payment in food from farmers who came to them for treatment.
9

Painters and other artists, like writers, also suffered from large depreciations in sums contracted, the gap between invoice and payment alone involving a ruinous loss for the artist, particularly after the autumn of 1922. Even before that, in May 1922, there had been a case where a sculptor offered a piece for 20,000 marks and found himself, in September of that same year, when it went on the market, required to keep to the price, so taking a 100,000 mark loss on the cost of materials alone. In the mean time, the dealer or gallery might well have set a new, inflation-adjusted selling price, which they received from the buyer and from which they alone benefited.
10
This was the brutal equation of the inflation.

Even quite well known artists of the avant-garde, such as George Grosz, young master of the grotesque, saw their fortunes take a downturn when the mark began to suffer its definitive breakdown. A Communist during the early years after the German revolution (though he left the party in late 1922 after witnessing the Soviet regime’s oppressive authoritarianism during an extended trip to Russia, summarising its brand of ‘Superman politics’ as ‘not for the likes of me’
11
) and an inveterate traducer of the old elite, Grosz was nonetheless supported by progressive establishment figures such as Harry Kessler. The resolutely liberal, trend-aware Count regularly visited Grosz’s studio in Berlin-Wilmersdorf, and put together a small collection of his work, clearly accepting Grosz’s own self-estimate as ‘the German Hogarth’.
12

All the same, Grosz and his friends seem to have found themselves in deep trouble as the inflation began to soar out of control. In his autobiography he describes their being
condemned to a diet involving the likes of turnip coffee
and
muscle pudding. A brief upturn came about only when Grosz was befriended by a chef at a Berlin restaurant. The man
had
exploited his connections to build up a hoard of fine foods, which gave him a lucrative sideline as a
black
marketeer. One night, after midnight and more than one double Kirsch, they left the restaurant and got into a taxi, hailed by a uniformed doorman in exchange for a million-mark tip.

Other books

Stranglehold by Robert Rotenberg
The Space Between Us by Jessica Martinez
Wandering Girl by Glenyse Ward
In Too Deep by Shannon, R.W.
Spirit Bound by Christine Feehan
The First True Lie: A Novel by Mander, Marina
Sex Slave at Sea by Aphrodite Hunt