Authors: Timothy H. Parsons
Tags: #Oxford University Press, #9780195304312, #Inc
threats. Although the Senate barred them from moving troops outside their provinces without permission, many found the temptation
to enrich themselves through self-serving wars irresistible.
Before 150 b.c., the Romans ruled only Sicily, Corsica, Sardinia,
and Spain directly. Although unapologetic conquerors, they were
also deft practitioners of soft power. When possible, Rome preferred
to exert infl uence through semiautonomous client kings whom the
Senate euphemistically termed “friends of the Roman people.” Putting aside their avowed disdain for kings, senators bestowed ivory
scepters, embroidered togas, and other markers of Etruscan royalty
on puppet rulers as symbols of their allegiance to Rome. More signifi cantly, the Romans often helped cooperative monarchs remain in
power with direct payments of coins and material goods. Acceptance
of these royal trappings and subsidies signifi ed that an ally deferred
to imperial authority, and the Romans interpreted any defi ance of
their will as an overt revolt. They also intervened freely in local succession disputes to replace unsuitable clients.
In the Greek portions of the empire, many city-states were so
cooperative that imperial administration was not a problem. But in
most other conquered territories the governors and their tiny staffs
needed local help to collect taxes and maintain order. In the west,
where there were fewer useful centralized institutions of authority, the Romans encouraged their creation by rewarding cooperative
allies with citizenship. The Romans also engaged in formal colonization by settling former soldiers in veterans’ colonies and providing
land grants to citizens and allies.
While tribute from client states and provincial taxes poured new
riches into Rome, the imperial windfall had an enormous hidden cost.
The common farmers, who made up the backbone of the early republican armies, faced bankruptcy because they could not compete with
cheap grain from Sicily and Spain. Many gravitated to the city of
Rome to take advantage of the free grain ration after wealthy and
connected families bought up their lands. This urban poor became a
dangerous rabble ready to support any conquering hero who promised to feed and entertain them.
32 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
Powerful proconsuls such as Pompey, Crassus, and Caesar played
to the mob and turned their legions into private armies by using imperial plunder to reward soldiers with pensions and land grants. Having
gained suffi cient strength and fame in the provinces, they marched
on Rome in a bid for absolute power. Imperial plunder thus had a
corrupting and corrosive impact on the republic. Countless problems
affl icted the late Roman Republic, but Caesar’s rise stemmed from the
inability of its representative institutions to incorporate its far-fl ung
provinces and this was a key factor in its demise. The slow transmission of orders and messages in the ancient world gave Roman generals and governors far too much power and autonomy, and the Senate
failed to fi nd a way to balance Rome’s representative institutions with
the inherent tyranny of imperial rule in the provinces.
Julius Caesar’s murder at the hands of the Senate in 44 b.c. appeared
to reaffi rm Rome’s republican values, but it paved the way for the rise
of his adopted son and heir, Octavian, who took the name Augustus
Caesar after coming to power in 31 b.c. Four years later, Augustus
made a show of giving up the dictatorial powers he had assumed during the struggle for power. The citizenry of Rome still elected consuls
and other lesser magistrates, but Augustus effectively brought the
republic to an end. He made himself a tribune for life, which gave him
the power to veto legislation and made his person sacred. Augustus
thus had absolute power over the city of Rome and its empire. He did
not claim to be a god during his lifetime, but by sanctioning the Senate’s deifi cation of his adoptive father, Julius Caesar, he established his
divine lineage. Adding the title
imperator
, an honorifi c that soldiers
voted to victorious generals, Augustus fi nally gave Rome an emperor
to go with its de facto empire (the principate). With a population of
forty million people, four million of whom were citizens, the Roman
Empire reached the height of its power under his despotic rule.
Facing few serious foreign threats, Augustus and the Julio-Claudian
emperors who succeeded him focused on securing virtually all of the
agriculturally productive regions of Europe and the Mediterranean
borderlands. They pushed imperial boundaries to their natural frontiers at mountain ranges, dense forests, deserts, and impassable bodies
of water. There was no formal line on a map marking the conclusive
limits of Roman territory. Rather, the Romans bounded the empire
with a network of roads, forts, and alliances with client kings.
Roman
Britain 33
Persia’s Parthian Empire was the principate’s only signifi cant rival
foreign power. But the “barbarians” of the west also became a serious
problem. It was the ambush and annihilation of three legions (fi fteen
thousand men) by northern Germans in the Teutoburg Forest in a.d.
9 that cooled the aging Augustus’s enthusiasm for further empire
building. The massacre drove home the reality that the incorporation
of unwilling frontier peoples was rarely worth the cost. Nonetheless,
the republican civil wars demonstrated that successful generals were
a much greater political threat.
Augustus had no direct male heir and left no formal system of succession, which meant most Julio-Claudians came to power through
adoption by their predecessors and the support of powerful allies in
the military. It was the Praetorian Guard who elevated Claudius to
the imperial throne by assassinating Caligula. While Claudius was
a reasonably moderate ruler, his adopted son and heir, Nero, was so
brutal and incompetent that powerful provincial governors drove him
to suicide in a.d. 68. The empire then lapsed into civil war as various
military leaders competed for the imperial purple. Order returned in
a.d. 69 when Vespasian, who had distinguished himself during the
Claudian conquest of Britain and the Jewish revolt, came to power.
The members of his Flavian dynasty and the following “fi ve good
emperors” ranged from enlightened despots to tyrants, but they presided over a century of stability and prosperity that Gibbon and later
historians romanticized as Rome’s golden age.
The Roman imperial administrative system came to full maturity
under the Julio-Claudian and Flavian dynasties, but the actual reach
of the emperors was short. Lacking the technology to issue immediate and direct orders, they relied on small personal staffs of slaves
and freedmen, trustworthy aristocrats, and a relatively small clerical
bureau to govern the empire. A formal bureaucracy did not develop
until early in the third century a.d. The Senate retained authority
over the Italian peninsula, and senatorial governors also commanded
garrisons in the peaceful territories. The emperor’s own men, who
were often equestrians (second-rank aristocrats), controlled legions
in frontier provinces. In most cases, their headquarters’ staffs provided the core of the administration. The emperors made law by
sending directives to provincial offi cials and responding to petitions
from their subjects. In their capacity as magistrates, governors relied
34 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
on Roman law in adjudicating cases involving Romans and followed
local precedent for lesser proceedings concerning noncitizens.
At the local level the actual mechanics of government varied widely.
Whenever possible, a city became the center of imperial administration because urban populations were the easiest to police and tax.
The Romans ruled through long-established city-states in the Greek
east, but Roman offi cials had to actively promote urbanization in the
western provinces. Imperial rule turned Spanish village communes
into formal cities with the rights of Roman citizenship (
municipia
)
and encouraged Gauls and Britons to abandoned fortifi ed strongholds
for new Roman-style towns. As in the city of Rome, urban populations elected governing magistrates from among the most wealthy
and infl uential members of the community, and these civil leaders
carried the burden of funding municipal operations. The emperors
also continued the republican practice of using veterans’ colonies to
create islands of Roman infl uence among conquered populations.
Governing the vast rural majority was more complicated. In the
western provinces, the Romans created the semblance of
civitates
by
lending money to community leaders to build capitals on the Roman
model. These anchored the administration of the surrounding countryside, and over time, many of their respectable classes became leading citizens of the empire.
The army was also a powerful instrument of assimilation under
the principate. Composed of long-serving professional soldiers who
were mostly volunteers, its base shifted from the Italian peninsula
to the provinces. Many of the principal recruits were the sons of
legionnaires from army camps in Spain, North Africa, and southern
Gaul, but others were auxiliaries drawn from subject communities
throughout the empire. The later Roman army had almost as many
auxiliary troops as it did regular Roman legionnaires, which lowered
the costs of imperial rule considerably. The Romans also disciplined
troublesome subjects by impressing them into ethnically based specialist units such as archers and light cavalrymen. German auxiliaries
from Batavia staged a signifi cant revolt in a.d. 69, but most subject
troops earned their Roman citizenship on discharge. Imperial military offi cials spread thousands of these romanized veterans throughout the empire. In both cases, they constituted a substantial prop to
Roman imperial rule.
Roman
Britain 35
The empire’s subjects bore primary responsibility for supporting
this 250,000-man standing army and the emperor’s vast personal
household. The steady fl ow of imperial loot and extortion meant that
citizens faced little in the way of direct taxes until late in the third
century a.d. In terms of currency alone, the republic minted roughly
fi fty tons of silver coinage per year in its fi nal decades, the equivalent
of half of the silver the Spanish imported from the Americas in the
sixteenth century a.d.13 Demands for revenue fell most heavily on
subject communities living along the empire’s network of roads, but
over time the imperial tax system captured a greater swath of the
rural population as it became more established and effi cient.
Metropolitan Rome and the Italian heartland were at the center of a ring of prosperous provinces consisting of Spain, southern
Gaul, North Africa, Asia Minor, Syria, and Egypt. These wealthy
territories, particularly in the east, funneled tax revenues to the
imperial core. Egypt and the African provinces also provided most
of the free grain for the city of Rome. Plunder aside, Britain and the
other outer provinces actually contributed comparatively little to
the metropolitan treasury, with the bulk of their resources going to
support military garrisons on the frontiers. Over time, Roman rule
gradually transformed the local economies of these outlying territories as revenue demands, military purchases, and free-spending
legionnaires stimulated trade and promoted the development of
provincial markets.
There are no surviving records of general tax rates under the principate, which means historians disagree on whether Roman demands
on their subjects were light or burdensome. At the very least, Roman
subjects paid a personal tax and a land tax. Wealthier men also paid
indirect levies on inheritances, houses, slaves, ships, and other forms
of property and commerce. The republic delegated direct taxation in
Greece and Gaul to private companies that paid for the right to collect
taxes in a given region. In order to extract more revenue than they
had to turn over to the state, these companies were often quite predatory. The principate ended some of the worst tax-farming abuses,
but its improved effi ciency in keeping track of the general population through censuses probably offset savings that taxpayers might
have gained from escaping the clutches of corrupt private collectors.
Romanized urban elites most likely accepted payment in agricultural
36 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
produce that could be sold to generate the coinage demanded by the
imperial treasury.
Aristocrats in Rome and the central provinces were the ultimate
benefi ciaries of this comparatively effi cient extractive system. These
were the senatorial and equestrian classes, which constituted less than
1 percent of the total imperial population. Senators, who numbered
six hundred under the early principate, owned vast rural estates that
made them the wealthiest men in the empire. Some also dabbled in
moneylending, but the equestrian class, which took its name from the
cavalrymen of the early republic, were the empire’s most prominent