Read The Blackwell Companion to Sociology Online
Authors: Judith R Blau
train, in bars, at parties, and in today's world over the telephone, by fax, and by e-mail. Much of what goes on in such interactions concerns the formation of
consensus. People tend to validate information by comparing and discussing
their interpretations with significant others, especially when the information
involved is complex ± as is always the case with social and political issues. Social psychological research has shown repeatedly that people prefer to compare their
opinions with those of like-minded individuals. As a rule, the set of individuals interacting in one's social networks ± especially friendship networks ± is relatively homogeneous and composed of people not too different from oneself.
However important interpersonal interaction is for the appropriation of col-
lective beliefs, it is not the only context in which this appropriation occurs.
Collective beliefs can be incorporated and conveyed in persuasive communica-
tion or media discourse, and can be assimilated independently of interpersonal
interaction. Of course, these sources of information are also used in interper-
sonal interaction. In Talking Politics, Gamson (1992b) reports the results of a
study of conversations conducted within groups of friends and acquaintances
whom he asked to discuss such issues as the Israeli±Arab conflict and affirmative action. One of his findings was that in these exchanges people use any kind of
information source available: newspapers, movies, advertisements, novels,
Why Social Movements Come into Being
279
rumors, their own and others' experience, and so on. Gamson distinguishes three
types of sources of information: media discourse, experiential knowledge (direct, from one's own experience, or indirect, derived from other people's experience), and popular wisdom (shared knowledge of what everyone knows). It is through
any of the resources that an individual can learn about the collective action
frame of a social movement or a social movement organization and appropriate
his or her own version of the injustice, identity, and agency frame. Gamson
suggests that the integrated use of all three sources facilitates the development of such frames. Media discourse provides information especially about who is to be
blamed for the situation; the two other sources, it turns out, are crucial for the interpretation and emotional loading of that information.
The Motivation to Participate in Collective Action
Adherence to a collective action frame at best produces the potential to participate. Actual participation requires a supply of activities individuals can take part in. There is a virtually endless variety of activities individuals can take part in: signing petitions, walking on demonstrations, wearing buttons or other symbols,
taking part in meetings or site occupations, taking part in strikes or boycotts, paying money, writing letters to political elites, being an officer of a movement organization, and so on. In order to create some system in this variety several
taxonomies have been proposed: moderate, militant, violent; high versus low
costs or risks; limited versus unlimited in time, etc. I hold that each form of
participation has its own motivational dynamics depending on its specific char-
acteristics. Moreover, individual sympathizers differ in terms of the activities they find attractive. In general, I maintain that social movement participation
must involve not only attractive goals, but attractive activities as well. Therefore, it is in the movement's interest to develop a broad supply of activities that
attracts a variety of sympathizers.
The attractiveness of an activity is dependent on the selective and collective
incentives an individual believes to be associated with that activity. Selective incentives relate to costs and benefits that differentiate between participants and non-participants. You are only spending time or money if you participate, you
only run the risk of being beaten up by the police if you participate, your friends will only blame you for not participating if you stay at home, and so on.
Sometimes movement organizations try to make participation more attractive
by providing selective benefits: a popular music group, a train ticket to the city where the demonstration is held, a T-shirt, etc. Authorities or opponents on their part can try to make participation less attractive by imposing costs upon participants. Collective incentives are related to achievement of the movement's goals and the extent to which participation in a specific activity contributes to goal achievement. Obviously, it is not enough for a goal to be important to a person, what is also needed is some likelihood of success. The problem with collective
action is that it is difficult to know to what extent an activity will have any
influence on authorities. In any event, the chances are low that an activity will have any impact if only a few people participate. Therefore, the likelihood of
280
Bert Klandermans
success is dependent upon the expected behavior of others. If too few people
participate it is unlikely that the activity will make any difference. As a consequence, it has been hypothesized that expectations about the behavior of others
play an important role in the decision to participate. If someone expects that
only a few people will participate his or her motivation to participate will be low.
In a way, the expectation about other people's behavior functions as a self-
fulfilling prophecy: if people believe that only a few will participate they will not be motivated to participate, and will thus make their own expectation true.
The Transformation of Potentiality into Action
Demand ± that is, people who adhere to a collective action frame ± is not
automatically turned into actual participation. Demand and supply must be
brought together. This is in fact what most action mobilization campaigns are
about: targeting potential participants and turning them into actual participants.
Obviously, a campaign will never be 100 percent successful in that regard. In the course of a campaign people may lose their sympathy for the movement. I have
labeled this conversion; a phenomenon that is more likely if countermovements
and/or authorities are mounting countercampaigns. On the other hand, organ-
izers may fail to convert sympathizers into participants because they fail to target or to motivate them. This I have called non-conversion. As the previous section
concentrated on motivating, I now focus on targeting.
Targeting sympathizers implies finding an answer to two strategic questions:
who are the sympathizers, and how can they be reached? These are, by the way,
two questions every attempt to persuade must find an answer to. Indeed,
sophisticated movement organizations such as Greenpeace have learned to
employ many of the strategies that have been developed in advertising. Social
networks are of crucial importance in this regard. Movement organizations have
two options here: they can try to co-opt existing networks or they can build new networks. Both strategies are mobilization efforts in themselves. Co-option is the easier strategy of the two, because it builds on existing commitments to organizations and networks that are part of the movement organization's alliance
system. There are risks, however. The co-opted organization may use the cam-
paign for its own ends or the leadership may for whatever reason decide not to
collaborate. The latter makes it more difficult for the rank and file to cooperate.
Yet co-option of existing networks, such as churches, unions, political parties, youth organizations, and the like, is frequently used, if only because it implies an answer to both strategic questions at the same time. On the one hand, it works
from the assumption that most members of the organization sympathize with the
movement; on the other hand, it is assumed that these sympathizers can be
reached through the organization's networks.
Building new networks implies the recruitment of people who are willing to
spend sometimes considerable amounts of time for a prolonged period as move-
ment activists. It will, therefore, require more effort on the part of the organization than co-option of existing networks, but once established the networks are
more reliable. The recruitment of movement activists is a process which is
Why Social Movements Come into Being
281
determined, on the one hand, by factors that influence who is being asked, and,
on the other hand, by factors that influence who agrees to serve as an activist
when asked. As for the first type of factors, a crucial determinant is someone's position in networks linked to the movement organization, or more specifically
to the movement organizer who is undertaking the recruitment effort. Move-
ment organizers tend to recruit first among the people they know, and often that suffices (Marwell and Oliver, 1993; Klandermans, 1997). After all, they don't
need many. According to Marwell and Oliver (1993), long-term activism is a
typical example of an activity with a decelerating production function. You need a few to maintain the network, but once you have those few the return from
having additional activists diminishes rapidly. Indeed, Marwell and Oliver argue that long-term activism is one of the forms of activism that must cope with free rider behavior. The latter point is of importance for the decision to serve as an activist or not. I maintain that the people who are asked to serve as activists
understand perfectly well that they are giving most of the sympathizers of the
movement a free ride, but they are prepared to do so because they care. Only
people who really care a lot are prepared to sacrifice for the others. In the words of Oliver (1984), they make the effort because they feel that `Ìf [they] don't do it, nobody else will.'' I hold that only people who strongly support the movement's
ideology and who feel responsible for maintaining and proselytizing the move-
ment and its ideology are prepared to make the effort of serving as movement
activists.
Conclusion
Social movements come into being because people who are aggrieved and have
the resources to mobilize seize the political opportunities they perceive. People join social movements because it gives meaning to their lives to fight together
with people they identify with for some social or political change. All these
different aspects are important in order to understand why social movements
come into being and why people join them. Grievances, resources, and oppor-
tunities on the one side, instrumentality, identity, and meaning on the other, are pieces of a puzzle we are only beginning to solve. Each of these concepts can be conceived of as the focal variable of a theoretical framework designed to investigate that variable. Grievance theory attempts to understand the demand side of
political protest; resource mobilization theory the supply side; and opportunity theory the interaction between the resulting social movement activity and its
political environment. Similarly, theories of identity formation and meaning
construction try to understand the generation and appropriation of collective
action frames by individuals; motivation theories the instrumentality of social
movement participation; and mobilization theories how potentiality is turned
into actuality. In this chapter, however, I have taken a synthetic approach and
discussed the ways in which these theories combine in the explanation of social
movements and social movement participation.
20
Social Movement Politics and
Organization
Debra C. Minkoff
In the popular imagination, social movements are conceptualized as dynamic
and dramatic mobilizations oriented toward such objectives as challenging the
state to recognize group rights, seeking public goods to improve the (middle-
class) quality of life, or stemming the tides of progressive social change. Periodic outbursts of activism ± from black civil rights protests in the United States to student democracy movements in China and anti-immigrant campaigns in Western Europe ± lend credence to this view of social movements as spontaneous and
emotional surges of collective action. In contrast, close to three decades of
sociological research on social movements demonstrates the many ways that
movement politics are structured organizationally at the local, national, and
increasingly transnational or global levels.
The juxtaposition of spontaneity and organization has been at the heart of
academic debates about social movements at least since the initiation (and
temporary ascendance) of the resource mobilization paradigm in the 1970s. In
the intervening years, organizational perspectives on social movements have
moved in and out of favor, as the field has embraced a broader turn in the
discipline toward concerns with identity, discourse, and culture. The limitations to such cultural perspectives are evidenced by the fact that, after cumulating
fairly detailed empirical knowledge of both contemporary and historical social
movements, scholars are beginning seriously to revisit the central insight of early resource mobilization theory: that organization matters. This ``return to organization'' makes sense in the context of a central practical reality facing contemporary movement-building and activism: the institutionalization of social
movements in the politics of advanced capitalist societies.
In seeking to understand this tension between social movement spontaneity
and institutionalization, the challenge is to re-establish the importance of organizations in social movement analysis without losing what we have learned about