Read The Great Depression Online

Authors: Benjamin Roth,James Ledbetter,Daniel B. Roth

The Great Depression (3 page)

BOOK: The Great Depression
4.06Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads
 
For many others, however, the New Deal was not extreme enough. Due in part to the surge in labor organizing made possible by the National Industrial Recovery Act, the Communist Party of the United States flourished in the 1930s. Its leaders advocated that the United States follow the Soviet model of revolution, eliminating capitalism and anointing the working class to run the society. It is doubtful that more than a few million Americans genuinely preferred this direction; actual CPUSA membership never topped one hundred thousand, and while party-affiliated organizations might have brought that number more comfortably into six figures, not all factions would have shared a Soviet-style society as a goal.
 
At the same time, there were many Americans who felt that if the fall of Democratic Capitalism was inevitable, Socialism in some form was preferable to other alternatives. And certainly Communists, Socialists, and their allies—particularly in trade unions—had a significant impact on social and cultural life during this period. Roth’s writing does not dwell on the politics of the Left, especially not before the introduction of the New Deal. Still, it is worth noting that Roth begins his diary on June 5, 1931; just six days earlier, one of the most violent confrontations in Youngstown’s history had taken place. A group of hundreds of Communists had been trucked into Youngstown from all across Ohio, Pennsylvania, and West Virginia to recruit members from its newly opened flophouses and soup kitchens and disrupt the city’s Memorial Day celebration. A violent clash with police ensued, and more than two hundred people were arrested and dozens injured and hospitalized.
 
Other extremists and populists also tempted America. The chameleon-like Father Charles Coughlin mesmerized millions of Americans over the radio, railing against Jews, capitalism, communism, Roosevelt, and the Federal Reserve system. In Youngstown the Ku Klux Klan had a particular appeal. Steel-industry jobs attracted workers from all over the world; according to the 1920 census, 60 percent of the city’s population had been born outside the United States. Such a large, and mostly Catholic, immigrant population made the Klan’s nativist message popular among Protestants, and in 1923 a majority of Youngstown’s city council was affiliated with the Klan. It was not fantasy to believe at this time that Socialists, Communists, Fascists, or extreme populists might take power in parts of the United States, whether by force or sympathy.
 
Not that such political ferment was Roth’s day-to-day concern. By dint of his professional standing and class, Roth was a natural-born Republican. He notes in the diary that he supports Hoover’s reelection in 1932, Alf Landon in 1936, and Wendell Willkie in 1940. For that reason it’s all the more remarkable that Roth became a public advocate for Roosevelt’s National Recovery Act in 1933. At one point that year he notes that he is doing so much on behalf of the NRA—including five speeches on a single Sunday—that he has time for little else. Yet within weeks he is questioning whether the NRA (or indeed any of the early New Deal programs) is doing any good and fears that the tremendous government debt may be doing harm. Supporting the NRA was, he explains, a simple civic duty, although reading between the lines, it seems clear that Roth was an effective public speaker and that he may well have developed a taste for the public spotlight (he would go on to hold elective office in Youngstown).
 
In our shorthand history of the period, we tend to think of a 1920s stock market boom—which Roth documents vividly, if retrospectively—followed by abject dust-bowl poverty, in which no one had money even for sufficient food or decent shelter, the Roaring Twenties replaced by haunting images from Dorothea Lange. Roth’s diary is a firsthand reminder that the reality was far more complex, that minibooms and minibusts existed during this period, in which post-1929 fortunes were being made as well as lost. Granted, the crash was one of the most devastating events in stock market history; the 1929 high in the Dow Jones Industrial Average of 381.17 would not be reached again for another quarter century. Yet in the period from 1929 to 1939, neither the stock market nor the economy as a whole went in one continuous direction.
 
Benjamin Roth’s writing asks a central question, namely, how should an honest, prudent person create wealth, protect it, and build it over the course of a lifetime?
 
It is fascinating to follow the evolution of Roth’s thinking about investment. As he watches the market mostly plunge in the 1931-1932 period, he seems mostly to feel that stocks are a sucker’s game. At the same time, he is tantalized by the prospect of bargain hunting among stocks—notably railroads and steel—that had lost nearly all their value, even though their underlying businesses seemed sure to rebound eventually. He also began to see that even though real estate seemed like a reliable investment—it is finite, tangible, and can be self-financing by charging rent—in a prolonged downturn, it could be devastating. The costs of upkeep, taxes, mortgage payments, and insurance are usually inflexible, whereas rental income could easily dry up if renters don’t have jobs. All around him buildings were being torn down because the owners would rather lose their investment than be forced into bankruptcy by their inability to pay property tax.
 
In the mid-thirties Roth begins to lay out an approach to investing based on controlling risk, maintaining liquidity, and protecting principle. Today, even casual investors are familiar with ways to describe the types of investment strategies toward which Roth gravitated: “value investing,” “buy and hold,” even “dollar-cost averaging.” But for Roth, these were not strategies to be bought off the rack; he had to build them himself—studiously, patiently, and, at least during the period covered by this book, entirely theoretically. He later regretted not having had the available cash to buy stocks when they hit historic lows and then recovered. (Roth would eventually come to buy individual stocks although, according to his son, only in very large companies, and always part of an investment portfolio that also included bonds and real estate.)
 
Roth’s preoccupation with personal finance makes this diary something of an anomaly in Depression-era literature. Visit the nicely appointed library or historical society in Youngstown (they are practically kitty-corner across Wick Avenue from one another) and you will find volumes about the struggles of Youngstown’s working class: the fight to unionize, the need for relief and decent housing. Much of Depression-era scholarship understandably adopts that lens. On the other end of the spectrum, the very wealthy of every time and place always have their lives documented, immediately by local media and later by biographers. If anything, the modern wealth-and-celebrity industry had its origins in the Depression, spawned by people’s need to be entertained out of their dreary realities. But if there is—to use a Depression-era phrase—a “forgotten man” of this period’s history, it is the honest, striving professional. There is no question that millions of Americans had a harder time during the 1930s than Benjamin Roth and his immediate family. Presumably, those hardest hit left little by way of a permanent record of their experience, because they died of starvation or were silenced by abject poverty. A step up from that level provides us with the Depression images we carry in our collective back pocket: dust-bowl refugees, urban soup-kitchen lines, Tom Joad and
The Grapes of Wrath
.
 
The endurance of those images is testimony to their truth, but Roth’s diary insists on an equal truth that is somewhat surprisingly absent from the nation’s 1930s yearbooks. Here is history told from the point of view of the Depression’s dramatically affected, but not its thoroughly trampled. At times—both when government aid is targeted directly at the poor and when a degree of prosperity returns in 1936—Roth seems a bit jealous that very little of the wealth being redistributed is ending up in the coffers of, say, lawyers such as himself. But he does not complain, and he does not propose a bailout for the professional class; instead, he redoubles his effort to understand the cycles of the economy and stock market and how best to invest. His mind is set on the potential for recovery, a particularly American predisposition.
 
That was not typical of his time; it seems fair to say that no one in the 1930s paid as much attention to the stock market as Benjamin Roth, unless they were actually invested in it. Strangely, though, it is far more typical of our own era, when (depending on how one measures it) about half of Americans have money invested in stocks and when a simple act like sitting in an airport lounge or getting on an elevator can mean being bombarded with opinions of buy, sell, or hold. We are, as a consumer spending-driven, service-oriented, market-led country, more like Benjamin Roth today than we were when he was writing, and certainly more than we are like the steelworkers who were his contemporaries. Benjamin is our CNBC Everyman, transported back in time.
 
Roth’s work has surprising literary power. He was not a professional writer; he was not immediately expecting a wide audience for these entries, and thus did not load them with fancy words, dazzling metaphors, or aphoristic sentences. (He did, though, have an ear for a cliffhanger ending to the individual notebooks.) Neither was he a trained economist or financial professional; especially in the early years of this diary, Roth seemed to genuinely struggle with some basics of investment and economics. He admirably held no illusions about his acquired expertise. As if constructing a kind of economic palimpsest, Roth would occasionally go back and annotate his earlier entries and did not hesitate to pronounce himself wrong. (Here, this hindsight commentary is indented on the page and marked with all-numeric dates [e.g., 8/13/52] to distinguish it from the real-time entries, where the full name of the month is spelled out.) Perhaps most important, though, Roth did not have the novelist’s or screenwriter’s luxury of knowing where the story was ultimately going.
 
Yet it is the very limitations of Roth’s expertise that make the diary so compelling to us today. The diary forces us to confront that buried, throbbing sensation that tells us that no matter how prosperous or lucky or cunning the American economy has been for the past century, we still don’t have definitive, universal answers to some very fundamental economic questions, large and small, that almost obsessed Roth. How much debt is too much debt—for a household, a company, or a government? What is the most secure way to guarantee return on an investment without exposure to excessive risk (whatever excessive risk is)? How much can government prop up private enterprise without creating a moral hazard that hinders market dynamism? Why can’t economies continue to expand at a steady, manageable pace without lapsing into destructive boom-and-bust cycles?
 
It is humbling and a little scary to realize that, since Benjamin Roth first began keeping his journal, millions and millions of man-hours have been spent framing, quantifying, and hypothesizing these questions without creating bulletproof answers or even much of a permanent consensus. Economics uses the statistics and ostensible precision one associates with, say, physics and astronomy. Yet to survey economic opinion on even seemingly simple questions gives the impression that economists as a group cannot consent to their equivalent of the hypothesis that the earth orbits the sun rather than the other way around.
 
It’s easy (and instructive) to read this diary and reassure ourselves about how many lessons policy makers learned from the 1930s and how many more economic safety mechanisms are in place. Insurance for the unemployed and guaranteed Social Security income for the elderly and infirm are standard features of the American economy; without them, the impact of current recessions on individuals could easily be as bad as it was during the Depression. On the federal policy level, the government guarantee of bank deposits up to a certain monetary amount makes panicky bank runs less likely and less damaging (though by no means impossible, and of course there are those who argue that such guarantees are harmful; see the above observation about the earth and the sun). And when banks do close, the process is orderly and the impact on the overall financial system minimized. Moreover, decades of experience with monetary policy have given the Federal Reserve—a relatively new institution in Roth’s time—much greater power in steering the economy away from extremes of inflation or unemployment. In the decade covered by this diary, Roth rarely takes the time and the perspective to assess the value of these lessons learned in the New Deal and beyond; he wasn’t, after all, seeing many permanent signs of their efficacy. Still, there is much in Roth’s descriptions to bolster the arguments of those who wish to argue that today’s economic managers are much better off than their counterparts in the thirties.
BOOK: The Great Depression
4.06Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

Firsts by Laurie Elizabeth Flynn
Vessel of the Demon God by Martin, Madelene
The Night Calls by Pirie, David
Little Mountain by Elias Khoury
Thicker Than Water by Brigid Kemmerer
Dead Madonna by Victoria Houston