Worldly Philosopher: The Odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman (82 page)

Read Worldly Philosopher: The Odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman Online

Authors: Jeremy Adelman

Tags: #General, #20th Century, #History, #Biography & Autobiography, #Social Science, #Business & Economics, #Historical, #Political, #Business, #Modern, #Economics

BOOK: Worldly Philosopher: The Odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman
3.38Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

Families, especially of the well-heeled, nearing-affluent sort, often have their favorite spots for vacations. Sometimes these are the grandparents’ home, sometimes a country house. For itinerants like the Hirschmans, there was no single destination. But there was one constant: whether it
was Boston, Bogotá, or Bahia, the beach was a favorite spot to relax. This idea of vacationing, drawn from memories of a childhood on the sands of the North Sea, reproduced itself in the Hamptons, on Cape Cod, and in Santa Monica. Once, while Sarah recounted her mixed feelings about family visits to Los Angeles, she was about to catalogue what she disliked about the city when Albert chimed in: “Unless it was to the beach.” This was in August 2005, by which point he was all but inaudible and incoherent; yet these words shone through, and to drive home the point, he repeated them. A legacy that allows us to reconstruct some sense of physical self-regard are the family photographic albums, which are filled with records of beach vacations. Because Albert was most often the man behind the lens, we have fewer images than we might like for such an exercise. But it is nonetheless revealing that when he did step out for a focus shot, he did so with performative élan and composure, what they call in German
Haltung
: always keep up a certain poise, never let yourself go or be caught by surprise. The pose, in this sense, was a question of dignity and can easily come across to our eyes as narcissism. Here is more
amour propre
on display than
amour de soi
. By the same token, there is no evidence of an effacing subject caught by surprise with a swollen midriff. Nor do we have evidence of shame or embarrassment about narrow shoulders or spindly legs that a more self-conscious man might conceal with a towel. The fact was, Hirschman did not just have a striking body, he knew it. And not only was he unashamed to put it on appropriate display, he was more than happy to exhibit its abilities. He could hold a headstand, a pose that combined athleticism with playfulness, for an astonishingly long time.

Impressive for a man born a half-century earlier. Hirschman was also not above showing some of the buff of the sculpted figure and would occasionally pose accordingly.

Hirschman knew he was an attractive man. People, starting with his own mother, told him so. Albert Camus’ second wife, Francine, told Albert that he reminded her of her (then philandering) husband; Albert was vain enough to know that this should be taken as a compliment. Even by then, Camus was an emblematically photogenic intellectual—made even more famous by the 1947 picture by Henri Cartier-Bresson of the
existentialist with cigarette and upturned trench-coat collar. Hirschman was also a smoker, though his was a social habit; perhaps the cigarette was, as in the Camus portrait, another prop for the vanities. The resemblance of Camus to Hirschman is hard to miss: the hairstyle, the lined forehead, clean-shaven with almost movie-star looks.

If he thought well enough of his physique, Hirschman cared as much about what covered it. It’s hard to say which part of the letter that Machiavelli wrote to Francesco Vettori in 1513 Hirschman liked more: the idea of conversing with ancient philosophers after a hard day scrabbling for a living, or the ritual of dressing up beforehand. What we do know is that Albert never dressed down, and his refinery made an impression. Perhaps it was the figure on which his clothes hung; perhaps it was the clothes themselves. Either way, his Columbia graduate students admired the fit of the Brooks Brothers shirts and jackets. By the 1970s, he had abandoned that rather staid look for something more casual but no less noteworthy—loose-fitting, silk-blend jackets procured from a clothier behind the Odéon in Paris. The tie was now a thing of the past, but the new combination gave him, if anything, even more flair. In so many of my conversations with old acquaintances, his apparel was memorable—as if a counterpoint to his equally unforgettable pausing, almost murmuring voice, which some took for a stutter. Robert Darnton, himself no slouch when it came to attire, recalled how Albert “liked to cut a figure sartorially” and how much he enjoyed entering a French restaurant appropriately garbed to eat and talk well.
2

With an attitude to life such as this one, it is not surprising that Hirschman aged without having to give up some of the traits of youth. The degeneration in his features from childhood to mature manhood was at most incremental, and one can still see the uncanny mixture of the twinkling eyes of the curious opportunist and the visage of the dreamer, about which so many people commented, into his seventies; he could still reach an Alpine glacier long after retiring. True, the forehead grew more lined, the swept back hair thinned out. But the breathless grace and easy self-regard remained.

  CHAPTER 18
 
Disappointment

It is only our conception of time that makes us call the Last Judgment by that name; in fact it is a permanent court-martial.

  
FRANZ KAFKA

N
o sooner did
The Passions and the Interests
come out in 1977 than Albert and Sarah went to Russia for ten days. These were the waning hours of détente. Hedrick Smith’s prize-winning
The Russians
dominated the
New York Times
best-seller lists, but East-West relations were turning frosty over human rights. The Hirschmans’ trip was an opportunity for Sarah to reconnect with her native tongue and share the pleasures of seeing Russian plays in Russian with Albert. Sarah promised to translate. Their white-night meanderings—through dilapidated churches, days in the Hermitage Museum, fancy (and overpriced) meals, discrete nudging of each other to point out the books people were reading, and gazing through car windows at passing potato farms—eventually took them to the forests outside Vladimir. One Sunday, they finally asked their driver about the scattered garden plots in the countryside. He owned one himself, he explained, and invited them to visit his wife and two sons. “Our driver’s lot,” noted Sarah, “is a marvel of horticulture.” Forty by twenty-five meters, it was densely packed with vegetables and fruit. The strawberries were ripe, and the driver’s wife was preparing to make preserves, taking advantage of her vacation as a nursery school teacher to prepare for the winter and make some extra jars to sell to neighbors. “What a strange concentration on a wholly private pursuit for the citizens of a socialist state!” the diary of their trip concluded.
1
This observation about collective
and “private pursuits” was no casual, offhand remark. It was becoming an obsession.

Part of the obsession was directed at Albert’s fellow economists. Hirschman felt compelled to write to Mac Bundy, the president of the Ford Foundation, with some thoughts about his creed. Bundy had expressed an increasingly common disparaging view of the dismal profession: economists enjoyed “the inside track” in thinking about development—and he was deeply unhappy about this. Hirschman did not disagree with him about “the preeminence of the economist as a policymaker.” The drive to make behavior calculable and predictable had narrowed the sphere of what economists might consider economic. But, by the same token, the other social sciences neglected problems of concern to economists. Hirschman considered it pointless to get outraged at or exhort economists directly. Economists were too important to the business of problem solving. Rather, he urged “developing some countervailing power on the part of other social scientists” in order to enrich economic thinking.
2
He wore his credentials like a badge, though he knew he stood orthogonal to his discipline.
3

In the ensuing years, it became a mission to clear new ground for a more connected social science. The general sense of crisis and breakup of intellectual coordinates pushed Geertz and Hirschman to redirect the concerns of the School of Social Science away from the strong focus on developing societies to address, starting in 1977, advanced industrial societies. Perhaps Hirschman’s return to Berlin played a role as well. For the first time, European social scientists such as Alessandro Pizzorno and Claus Offe came to the school. Offe’s arrival was a pretext for Hirschman to dust off his unused German—which struck the young sociologist as a throwback to his grandparents’ tongue; Hirschman’s German had fossilized in a bygone era. Also, America’s leading liberal philosopher, John Rawls, joined the assembly for one semester. The group composed of Pizzorno, Offe, Rawls, Martin Shefter, Herbert Gintis, and Robert Cooter decided to meet Monday evenings in peoples’ homes. With a backdrop dominated by the buzz about the “crisis of the welfare state,” spreading strikes, the meltdown of New York City’s finances, and winters of discontent,
the Monday-evening group fastened on the hot topic of the “governability of modern democracy.” By any reckoning it was an impressive group. Rawls and Offe (a student of the German philosopher, Jürgen Habermas) led an evening’s discussion of Habermas’s
Legitimation Crisis
; another evening Hirschman and Pizzorno spearheaded a talk of Mancur Olson’s
The Logic of Collective Action
.

Having diagrammed his views of the original arguments for capitalism
before
its triumph, and prompted by the Monday-evening gatherings in Princeton, Hirschman sat down to settle scores with Mancur Olson’s highly influential 1965, almost prophetic work,
The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups
, a near-biblical argument for a model of capitalism
after
its triumph. More than any other, Olson’s book nurtured the emerging field of institutional economics and popularized coinages such as “collective action problems” and “free-riders.” The nuts and bolts had been around for a while; Olson’s accomplishment was to pull them together into a single, indomitable, and to some depressing, intervention that anticipated many of the arguments that would gain currency in the gloom of the 1970s. At the heart of Olson’s argument was that modern societies create incentive systems that induce individuals to invest their energies in private goods but thwart the pooling of these efforts to create public goods. Moreover, these propensities were bound by an immutable “logic.” Efforts to coax people into collective action to provide public goods inevitably lose their steam as defectors respond to the incentives to “free ride” on the backs of others. In contrast, individuals don’t free ride when groups support private goods—a conclusion that gave ballast to a rising neo-conservative movement that advocated private solutions to social problems. Olson did not necessarily think that free-riding was driven purely by selfishness; it was the government provision of public goods that made free-riding a rational response. Some neo-cons simply touted the virtues of private greed. Either way, the result was an impossibility theorem about sustained collective solutions to social problems that explained why there could be no real influential mass action.
4

Olson’s book burrowed under Hirschman’s skin; the optimism and mystery of his Hiding Hand of the 1960s was losing to the bleak, iron
logic of the Invisible Hand of the 1970s.
5
It did not help that Olson had written a wrong-headed review of
Journeys toward Progress
, which presented Hirschman’s work as a catalogue of corruption, misgovernment, and hopelessness in Latin America.
Exit, Voice, and Loyalty
was a book that reviewers frequently set alongside Olson’s
Logic of Collective Action
as a counterpoint: the former explaining collective action movements while the latter pointed to their futility. One reviewer took
Exit
to task for failing to take fuller account of Olson’s demolition of the prospects of “voice,” which left Hirschman steaming; Hirschman was nothing if not sensitive to reviews.
6

Ten years after the publication of these counterpoints in the social sciences, the mood seemed to have declared Olson the winner. By 1978, the spirit of ’68, which had been so decisive for
Exit, Voice, and Loyalty
, was looked upon as a rash, aberrant, quixotic outburst. The rising tide of neo-conservatism was only too pleased to announce its triumph as the restoration of a natural order. Hirschman took advantage of one evening’s discussions at Cliff Geertz’s house to take Olson as Exhibit A for what he would then spend the next decade and a half trying to expose: the rhetoric and politics of the ideological underpinnings of the Right.

Hirschman picked apart Olson’s claims. There were empirical “flaws.” Olson did not deal with entrepreneurship. He ignored leadership and neglected “explosions of public activity.” Olson’s principal points had been “well known since Hume”; Hirschman was always pleased to demolish claims to originality with a nod to the classics (over whom he was accumulating an increasingly formidable command). But none of this was especially important, and Hirschman knew it; Olson
had
observed a phenomenon that could not be so easily waved away: the resilience of private solutions to public problems. Even more: Hirschman did not disavow them. He acknowledged the book’s “merits,” the chief one being that he “debunks [the] idea that interest group formation is almost automatic and that one can somehow rely on these groups and their interplay for [a] public interest outcome.” He also applauded the effort to explain individuals’ decisions “not to join” as “not necessarily apathy but the free ride phenomenon.” Olson’s was not an argument easily dismissed by invoking
empirical exceptions or even more a rival ideology. The issue was that Olson presumed a necessary divide, a basic partition between exit and voice, markets and democracy, which left no room for Hirschman’s mixed model of Man vulnerable to contingency and possibilities that kept toppling any
logic
(a word that made him shiver) governed by a single, if powerful, drive.
7

His notes on Olson reveal someone who had lost his customary cool. The “paradox of voting” (why do people bother voting if any single ballot is trivial?) “is a paradox only if it is considered that participation is costly,” Hirschman scribbled vigorously. So, he went on: the “act of voting = people exercising sovereignty for one day = feasts of fools.” This was, he believed, not just empirically false but a caricature. There are, after all, he wrote to himself, activities whose “striving … cannot be neatly separated from possessing [an] object.” He brought in Pascal’s thoughts on food, play, prayer, and politics where a “cost-benefit calculus becomes impossible.” Having seen the distortions caused by over-confident “theories” of development planning dressed in a similar cost-benefit calculus, this must have come across as déjà vu. But this challenge was more daunting—which helps explain the unusually emphatic reactions. “Olson is wrong”: he had captured one point, one response, among the several that people could choose. He had contrived a “theory” to make the contingent, the chosen, seem inevitable, converting one possibility into a necessity.
8

Other books

Destiny: Book of Light by Allen, Paul
FATHER IN TRAINING by Susan Mallery
SECRETS Vol. 4 by H. M. Ward, Ella Steele
Naughty by Velvet
Confessions of a Queen B* by Crista McHugh
Perchance to Dream by Robert B. Parker
Deceived by Stella Barcelona
Act of Passion by Georges Simenon