Authors: Timothy H. Parsons
Tags: #Oxford University Press, #9780195304312, #Inc
and the hope of manumission, but only the most pious owners made
this a viable option.
Still, the Umayyads were no more exploitive than their imperial
predecessors or contemporaries, and their demise came at the hands
of fellow Muslims rather than rebellious non-Muslim subjects. Ruling for less than a century, they were comparatively poor empire
builders. The early caliphate was not set up to manage a sprawling
intercontinental empire, nor were the Umayyads equipped to divide
the enormous spoils of empire or govern large numbers of alien subjects. In this sense, the Umayyad imperial state simply grew too large
and too fast to be stable.
Most of the Umayyad caliphs failed to grasp the inherent risks of
empire and gave their generals and governors a free hand to acquire
new territories. Umar II was one of the few rulers to understand the
implications of subjugating so many non-Muslims and had grave
doubts about the sustainability of the Umayyad expansion. Ruling
from only 718 to 720, he concluded that the caliphate was too reliant
on plunder. The enormous sums that his predecessors spent on public
works, mosques, palaces, and military operations were not sustainable
without constant fl ows of loot. The conquest of Sind may have netted the caliphate 120 million dirhams, but it took at least 60 million
dirhams per year to pay the stipends of the three hundred thousand
soldiers in the Umayyad armies.9 Moreover, looting was not a sustainable revenue source; a conquered community could only be plundered so many times. The
jizya
(poll tax on non-Muslims) provided
some relief, but this obligation theoretically ended with conversion.
Fiscal necessity worked against this, and perceptive caliphal offi cials
warned that the continued imposition of the
jizya
on
mawali
converts undermined the regime’s legitimacy.
80 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
Umar therefore tried to keep the caliphate solvent by taking a
break from empire building. Cognizant of the underlying costs of
imperial expansion, he demobilized surplus military units and seriously considered withdrawing from recently conquered territories in
Sind, Transoxiana, and Spain. He also reduced princely allowances
and imposed the
kharaj
(land tax) on Muslims who purchased land
from non-Muslims. Umar recognized that discrimination against the
mawali
was dangerous and moved to exempt them from the
jizya
.
Seeking to offset the resulting loss of revenue, he tried to introduce
more regular and effi cient taxation policies.
Although Umar’s reforms made considerable sense, he did not live
to see them through. Caliph Hisham, who ruled from 724 to 743,
did not share his predecessor’s concerns about the costs of empire.
He broke an implicit truce with the Byzantines and launched new
expansionist campaigns in Central Asia, North Africa, and France.
Although his forces initially won a few victories, internal revolts
and stiffening resistance on the frontiers soon led to disaster. The
Umayyad military fortunes turned in the late 720s when Turkish
invaders wiped out entire armies in Khurasan, while widespread popular resistance forced them to retreat from India. In the west, Frankish forces under Charles Martel turned back an invading Muslim
army at Poitiers in 732.
The cost of Hisham’s futile campaigning alienated the soldiery
and fanned popular dissatisfaction with Umayyad rule. This was particularly true in Khurasan, where Umayyad governors reimposed the
jizya
on converts, but there was also signifi cant unrest among the
Berbers in North Africa. Angered by the
jizya
and abusive Arab governors who seized conscripts and slaves as tribute, Muslim Berbers
launched a massive revolt in 739 that forced Hisham to send an army
of one hundred thousand men to Tunisia. When the Berbers won a
decisive victory by exploiting tensions between local Arabs and Syrian units in the expeditionary force, the caliph had to rush even more
troops to North Africa. The overextended Umayyad generals fi nally
defeated the Berbers in 742, but the toll of almost ten years of continuous campaigning meant that Hisham’s imperial adventures were
no longer sustainable.
Exhaustion, mounting losses, and economic retrenchment resulting from military reverses opened deep divides among the Arab
Muslim
Spain 81
military elite. The Syrian fi eld army’s signifi cant reverses in India,
Central Asia, Asia Minor, North Africa, and France meant that it
could no longer prop up the Umayyad regime. More seriously, tensions between the Yaman and Qays tribal cliques became so bitter
under Hisham that incoming governors routinely removed offi cials
from rival factions and imprisoned and tortured their predecessors
under the guise of recovering embezzled funds. The demise of the
Syrian fi eld army, which consisted primarily of Yamanis, through
overuse and military defeat created a dangerous power vacuum in
Syria. The resulting civil war in 744 cost the Umayyads the caliphate. The dispersion of the surviving Syrian units throughout the
provinces opened the way for rival Umayyad princes, backed by
ambitious generals, to lay claim to power.
Their fratricidal infi ghting distracted the Umayyads from an
emerging threat in the east where a rival dynastic power organized
Persian
mawali
and surviving elements of the Khurasan fi eld army
into a powerful anti-Umayyad force. Angered by hypocritical tax
policies, the Central Asian converts found common cause with disgruntled Arab soldiers who had married into local families. Abu alAbbas Abdullah ibn Muhammad, the founder of the Abbasid dynasty,
assumed control of this popular revolt by virtue of his descent from
Muhammad’s paternal uncle and his adopted ties to Ali’s son. This
pedigree appealed to Muslims who still believed that the
umma
should
be led by a descendant of Muhammad through Ali, but the Abbasids
drew their largest following by championing a universalistic nonethnic version of Islam that recognized non-Arab converts as Muslims in good standing. Through this, they espoused an anti-imperial
ideology that promised a complete and conclusive escape from subjecthood to the
mawali
who still chafed under Umayyad discrimination. Fighting under black banners that suggested that a messiah or
mahdi
from Ali’s line would return to usher in a golden age of justice, the Abbasid forces swept westward out of Khurasan and defeated
the last Umayyad caliph, Marwan II, in 750. They slaughtered all the
Umayyad nobles they could fi nd and desecrated the tombs of every
Umayyad caliph except for that of the pious Umar II.
Although the caliphate technically lasted until the Mongol invasion of 1258, the Abbasids transformed it substantially. They shifted
its capital from Damascus to Baghdad and drew more heavily on
82 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
Persian systems of imperial rule. The caliphate thus became fundamentally less Arab as easterners assumed greater roles in the
bureaucracy and court. Yet the Abbasids continued to struggle with
the complexities of imperial rule. There was no further institutional
discrimination against non-Arab Muslims, but the “Abbasid revolution” did not make the caliphate less imperial from the perspective
of its non-Muslim subjects. Indeed, Christians in Lebanon and Egypt
proved particularly restive under Abbasid rule.
Although their victory over the Umayyads was total and complete, the Abbasids failed to wipe out their rivals entirely. Fleeing the
carnage in Damascus, Prince Abd al-Rahman, a grandson of Caliph
Hisham and the son of a Berber concubine, sought refuge with his
mother’s people in North Africa before crossing into Iberia. Taking
control of Al-Andalus, Abd al-Rahman laid the groundwork for an
independent Muslim Iberian state that lasted for two hundred years.
Raised to a caliphate by his ambitious descendant Abd al-Rahman III,
this Umayyad outpost ruled a substantial Christian majority. These
Iberians were particularly vulnerable because they had been subjects of the Roman and Visigothic imperial states. By necessity, the
Muslim conquerors appropriated and adapted the imperial institutions of their predecessors to exploit the ancestors of the Spanish
conquistadors.
The people whom Tariq ibn Ziyad and Musa ibn Nusayr conquered
in 711 were not Spanish in the modern national sense. Roderic and
his nobles were the heirs of the “barbarians” who brought down the
Roman Empire. Chapter 1 has shown how an armed migration by the
Huns in the fourth century forced loosely organized bands of Goths
to seek refuge within the Roman frontiers. Although the Gothic
leader Alaric sacked Rome, the ancestors of the Visigoths eventually
became relatively reliable Roman allies. As
foederati
, they provided
military service in return for protection and a one-third share of the
revenue from large Roman estates in the region.10
Though technically barbarians, the Visigoths became an important prop of the later Roman Empire. Emperor Honorius, who had
allowed Roman Britain to slip away, granted them the right to settle in
Aquitania in recognition of their assistance during further barbarian
invasions. Pressure from the Franks early in the sixth century forced
them into Iberia, where they challenged an earlier group of Germanic
Muslim
Spain 83
invaders known as the Sueves. The Visigothic kings made Toledo the
royal capital, but they pragmatically kept Roman offi cials at their posts.
They did not consolidate their hold on the peninsula until the midsixth century, when King Leovigild defeated the Sueves and drove
the Byzantines from the southern regions of the peninsula.
Like many Roman successor states, Visigothic Iberia was unstable.
Political succession was a problem because the Visigothic monarchs
were, at least in theory, elected warrior kings. Most aspired to become
hereditary rulers, and their dynastic ambitions led to constant friction with the nobility. As a conquering elite that probably numbered
no more than two hundred thousand people, the Visigoths claimed
sovereignty over an indigenous population approximately eight
million strong.11 As foreigners and outsiders, they were an imperial
power, and their limited numbers forced them to rely on HispanoRoman landowners to rule the Iberian majority. Living apart and
lacking the means and sophistication to impose their own customs,
the Visigoths relied on administrative institutions inherited from
the Romans. In this sense, the Roman Empire did not fall in Iberia
so much as it was simply taken over by the Visigoths. Keeping the
Hispano-Roman imperial machinery running as well as it could, the
Visigothic state did not govern or collect taxes directly until the late
seventh century.
The Visigoths were far less successful in preserving the economic
foundations of Roman Spain. The fragmentation of the empire into
smaller political units, coupled with widespread banditry and outright
anarchy, destroyed the networks of commerce and fi nance that made
Roman Iberia so rich. Plagues and warfare appear to have reduced
the peninsula’s population from six million to four million people by
the end of the seventh century.12 The Visigoths could not keep the
roads open and safe or prevent warlords from building strong points
to prey on villages and travelers. Consequently, farming communities in the Guadalquivir Valley, the economic heartland of southern
Roman Spain, fl ed their lands for the comparative protection of the
hills.
As in Britain, many Roman cities fell into decline, and those that
survived often consisted of decrepit Visigothic structures built on
Roman ruins. The breakdown of long-distance trade and the demise of
the Roman military garrison meant that coinage no longer circulated,
84 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
disrupting the peninsula’s market economy severely. The Iberian
grain and olive oil that once were important cash crops lost their most
lucrative markets in Italy, Gaul, and Britain, thereby forcing many
producers to fall back on subsistence agriculture. As a result, Iberian
import markets also dried up. These developments coincided with the
Byzantine retreat and suggest that the peninsula became relatively
isolated from the commerce of the wider Mediterranean world under
the Visigoths.
This overall insecurity probably promoted localism and accelerated Spain’s shift to a feudal economy, a process that was already
under way in the late Roman imperial era. Faced with the anarchy
of the Roman collapse, large numbers of peasant farmers most likely
turned their lands over to powerful elites in exchange for protection. In doing so they joined the slave laborers who worked the vast
Hispano-Roman estates, or
latifundia
, in serfdom. Tied to the soil,
they surrendered a share of their crops as rent in addition to paying the Roman poll tax to the Visigothic state. These feudal systems
of production generated only a fraction of the revenues of the late
Roman era, and the Visigothic nobility made matters worse by confi scating former Roman imperial estates and shrinking the kingdom’s