Authors: Timothy H. Parsons
Tags: #Oxford University Press, #9780195304312, #Inc
slow to follow the Iberian lead in exploiting the opportunities of the
New World, the English Crown still followed the Spanish example of
relying on private speculative interests to take the lead in overseas
empire building. In the Western Hemisphere, the resulting North
American settlement and West Indian plantation colonies had their
own particular characteristics, but they were relatively similar to
their Spanish American counterparts. In Asia, however, the British
East India Company was an entirely different kind of semiprivate
imperial power. The Dutch East India Company, which conquered the
Spice Islands and southern Africa, was its only real peer. The EIC’s
Indian empire differed markedly from Britain’s colonies in the Americas, thereby making it diffi cult to speak of the larger British Empire
as a single integrated institution.
The English monarchs, who had far less autonomy after the Glorious Revolution of 1688 than their Bourbon Spanish counterparts,
were most concerned with forging the United Kingdom. English
imperial entrepreneurs fi rst focused primarily on founding settlement colonies in Ireland. Sixteenth-century speculators such as Sir
Walter Raleigh, who later made a name for himself in the Americas,
carved out “plantations” around the northern city of Ulster for English and Scottish settlers. Citing the Roman colonies in Britain as an
inspiration, they claimed land in Ireland by right of conquest and
depicted conquered Irish populations as uncivilized barbarians lacking the capacity to make proper use of fertile soil. Unlike the Welsh
and Scots, who eventually became Britons, Irish Catholics largely
remained inassimilable imperial subjects. As a result, when the Act of
Union created the United Kingdom in 1707, Ireland became a de facto
colony under the jurisdiction of the British Parliament.
Distracted by their Irish project and the Thirty Years’ War, the
cash-starved Crown left it to private commercial interests to take the
Company
India 179
lead in overseas expansion. It used the royal charter, which conferred
a monopoly over all British trade in a given region, to convince entrepreneurs to accept the speculative risks of foreign ventures. Over time,
these loose alliances of merchants gave way to joint stock companies
that spread the risk of foreign trade and investment by raising capital
collectively. Some of their shareholders were active traders, but others were passive investors seeking the greater profi ts of foreign commerce without leaving the safety of home. A court of directors and
central offi ce in London delegated the authority to negotiate trading rights and commercial treaties to company governors and factors
who established forts and trading stations (factories) in foreign lands.
Ideally, the companies exchanged European manufactures for spices,
textiles, slaves, and other commodities, but in Asian markets they
often had to buy the most desirable goods with precious metals. The
expense of maintaining a fl eet of armed merchant ships and fortifi ed trade settlements was considerable, but the most successful fi rms
used their monopolies to turn a profi t. Technically, their charters only
applied to rival British fi rms, but the courts of directors went to the
great expense of raising private armies in an effort to force foreign
rivals to respect them as well. The Crown played no role in directing
their activities, but the chartered company model gave it an extremely
cost-effective means of projecting imperial power overseas.
For their part, the courts of directors used their charters to raise
capital for a wide variety of endeavors. Founded in 1581 as one of
the fi rst joint stock companies, the Levant Company futilely tried
to develop a secure overland commercial route to Asia. In the west,
the Virginia, Plymouth, and Massachusetts Bay companies purchased
charters in the early seventeenth century giving them the right to
establish speculative settlement colonies in North America. Later in
the century, the Royal Company of Adventurers and the Royal African Company sought gold and then slaves in West Africa.
In the Americas, British charter holders and would-be empire
builders had to confront the formidable but precarious Spanish
Empire. Elizabeth I provided a measure of support for Francis Drake
and Thomas Cavendish, but often it took force to make up for the
Spanish, Portuguese, and French head start in the Western Hemisphere. Elizabeth therefore also quietly encouraged Drake and his
peers to raid Spanish shipping. Taking advantage of Spain’s growing
impotence, British imperial entrepreneurs followed in the wake of
180 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
these privateers to stake out settlement and plantation colonies in
the sugar-producing islands of the West Indies and the most promising regions of coastal North America. They purchased their charters
on the assumption that royally sanctioned monopolies on settlement
and trade would make them great lords in the New World.
Yet the Spanish imperial model was unworkable in North America
because the indigenous population was too sparse and vulnerable to
disease to play the role of exploitable subjects. After an initial period
of relatively peaceful coexistence, British settlers virtually wiped out
most coastal Amerindian societies through warfare and enslavement.
Still, the population of British North America grew from one hundred thousand to roughly two and a half million people between the
mid-seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.8 Taken as a whole, this
massive overseas migration of western Europeans and unwilling
African slaves produced an entrenched and expanding permanent
British population in the Western Hemisphere.
In the east, the chartered company system never produced permanent settlement colonies. Most Asian societies were far too powerful
and resistant to Old World diseases to suffer the fate of the Inkas.
Moreover, the British East India Company was surprisingly impotent
when its representatives fi rst arrived in Asian waters. Its royal charter gave it a monopoly on all British commerce east of the Cape of
Good Hope, but the EIC’s 218 original stockholders were so severely
undercapitalized that they had to share the costs of trading stations
in the Spice Islands with Dutch partners. Further east, the Chinese
refused to admit EIC ships to their ports, and in Japan Company traders ineptly tried to sell coarse English woolens to the silk-wearing
Japanese. Prospects with the Company were so bad during this early
period that its directors recruited many of their clerks and accountants from orphanages and charity schools.9
The Dutch, conversely, were the dominant western power in Asia
for most of the seventeenth century. Emerging from the Thirty Years’
War as an expansionist commercial power, the Dutch Republic organized Amsterdam-based companies trading with Asia into the Dutch
East India Company. Chartered in 1602, the VOC had considerably
more leeway than its European rivals in fi ghting wars and conducting
diplomacy. Its fortifi ed trading settlements in the Spice Islands and
commercial contacts with Mughal India gave it the lead in capturing
the lucrative long-distance trade with Europe.
Company
India 181
The Dutch East India Company guarded its advantages jealously
and was often ruthless in its pursuit of profi t. For a time it tolerated
the EIC’s fumbling attempts to gain a portion of the pepper trade,
but it lost patience with the British when they interfered with Dutch
interests. Things turned ugly in 1623 when the VOC executed ten
to fi fteen of the EIC’s employees on the island of Ambon. Unable to
stand up to the Dutch militarily, the EIC turned its attention to the
South Asian subcontinent, where no European company was strong
enough to monopolize trade with the Mughal Empire or the independent rulers of southern India.
The Company fi rst realized India’s economic potential when it
captured a Portuguese ship loaded with high-quality South Asian
textiles. In 1608, it set up its fi rst trading station at Surat, in western India, and opened another three years later at Masulipatam, on
the southern coast. While these factories gave the EIC entry into the
well-established Indian Ocean textile trade, it sought more direct
access to the weavers in the interior to avoid the higher costs on the
coast. But the Portuguese initially convinced the Mughal emperor
Jahangir to deny the Company trading privileges on the grounds that
it was just a minor power. It was only when the EIC’s naval forces
destroyed a rival Portuguese fl eet, thereby demonstrating its usefulness as an ally, that the Mughals granted the British full access to
Indian markets.
The Company initially purchased textiles to trade for spices in
Indonesia, but it soon realized that there was a market for these fabrics in Europe. By the 1660s, its annual imports to Britain amounted
to over four million square meters of cloth with a total value of nearly
three-quarters of a million pounds. The East India Company sold
most of this material at London auctions, but riots by English weavers in the 1690s led the Crown to impose protective tariffs on Asian
textiles. In 1721, it allowed the Company to import only high-quality
printed Indian calicos for reexport to Europe. These restrictions led
the EIC to diversify into trading in indigo and saltpeter.
The increasing importance of the Indian trade led the Company
to seek more permanent bases on the subcontinent. In the south, the
EIC shifted from Masulipatam to a small fi shing village that grew
into Madras. Company offi cials also abandoned Surat for the island
of Bombay, which Charles II acquired from the Portuguese as part
of the dowry for his marriage to Catherine of Braganza. In Bengal,
182 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
the Company established its original factory on the upper Hugli
River, but Mughal pressure forced it to shift to the more strategically
located coastal villages that became Calcutta. The court of directors in
London appointed a council of merchants to run each of these trading
stations, which came to be known as presidencies.
The Company’s footprint in India was originally quite small, with
each presidency rarely having more than one hundred employees. EIC
traders therefore relied heavily on Indian brokers and middlemen to
serve as translators and provide information on markets, weights and
measures, and currency. In Bengal, the most important of these local
brokers became salaried Company employees responsible for overseeing a network of rural agents who in turn contracted with weavers
and farmers to supply textiles, raw silk, indigo, opium, and a range
of other commodities. These lower-ranking Indian intermediaries did
not work directly for the Company and made their money largely on
commissions.
Similarly, the EIC’s European salary levels were so low that the
court of directors allowed its employees to support themselves through
private trading. The most senior offi cials had the privilege of exporting goods on Company ships, but the royal monopoly on commerce
with metropolitan Britain forced them to concentrate on Southeast
Asian and Chinese markets. This tied the East India Company into
larger Asian trading networks. Over the course of the seventeenth
century, these offi cial and private trading initiatives also drew the
East India Company ever deeper into the affairs of the subcontinent.
Seeking to cut out the middlemen who drove up prices, Company
employees became more involved in Indian commerce, investment,
and local politics. Many favored their private interests in undertaking ventures that did not have the approval of the court of directors
in London.
The breakdown of Mughal authority in the 1730s and rising tensions with the VOC and the French Compagnie des Indes, which was
a signifi cant force in southern India, opened the way for the Company to become a territorial Indian power. Plassey was actually a side
note to the Seven Years’ War, a largely European confl ict that took
on a global dimension when France and Britain became involved.
Forced to protect its commercial interests in India, the British government stiffened the EIC’s small army, which consisted largely of
hired Indian soldiers, with regular frontline regiments. The court of
Company
India 183
directors would have preferred to remain neutral during the confl ict
with the French, but this vital metropolitan backing provided the
means for Clive and other ambitious employees to compete with the
Bengali
nawabs
and other regional powers.
The Company’s resulting Indian empire looked nothing like the
British settlement colonies of the Americas. The New World territories were technically the property of the Crown, which meant
that monarchs had the prerogative of intervening directly in their
affairs. This was in sharp contrast to the private empire in India that
answered to the EIC’s two thousand proprietors (shareholders owning more than fi ve hundred pounds’ worth of stock) who elected the
managing court of directors. This governing body was hardly the sort